By Kevin E. Noonan --
In response to an earlier post on Novartis' challenge to the Indian Patent Office's decision not to grant a patent on its anticancer drug Gleevec® (see "Indian Supreme Court to Rule on Gleevec Patent"), a reader opined that we should appreciate the erudition and wisdom of the patent official in Mumbai responsible for the denial. He helpfully sent along the decision granting a compulsory license to Natco for Bayer's anticancer drug, sorafenib tosylate (sold as Nexavar®). A review of the decision indeed provides insights into how officials in India interpret the provisions of its law regarding compulsory licenses. Such a review also suggests that what may appear to produce a "Catch 22" for Western drug companies can reasonably be considered to be a straightforward application of sound principles in the best interests of the Indian citizenry.
The provision of Indian law at issue is Section 84 of the Patent Act:
84. Compulsory licenses. –
(1) At any time after the expiration of three years from the date of the grant of a patent, any person interested may make an application to the Controller for grant of a compulsory license on patent on any of the following grounds, namely –
(a) that the reasonable requirements of the public with respect to the patented invention have not been satisfied . . .
. . .
(ii) the demand for the patented article has not been met to an adequate extent or on reasonable terms . . .
(b) that the patented invention is not available to the public at a reasonably affordable price . . .
(c) that the patented invention is not worked in the territory of India.
With regard to this requirement, the Indian Controller of Patents set out the competing claims of the compulsory license applicant and the patentee. The applicant alleged that there were ~20,000 liver cancer patients and ~9,000 kidney cancer patients (the populations that benefit from the drug), and that assuming 80% demand there would be a need for about 23,000 bottles of the drug per month to satisfy the demand. The facts (albeit disputed by Bayer) presented showed no bottles imported into India in 2008, ~200 bottles in 2009 and that there was no evidence for import in 2010. The significance of these dates and amounts are that the Indian government granted Bayer a patent on the active pharmaceutical ingredient in Nexavar® in 2008, and the Controller assessed Bayer's behavior in fulfilling the "reasonable requirements of the public" during that time. It was also significant that Bayer did not produce the drug in India, explaining the focus on bottles of imported drug. The Controller's decision mentioned that failure to manufacture the drug in India was evidence that Bayer had not "taken adequate steps to . . . make full use of the invention."
In addition, and in what is the crux of the matter, the Controller stated that the drug is "exorbitantly priced" and out or reach of most of the people. The price of the patented drug was quoted in the decision as being Rs.2,80,248/- per month and Rs.33,65,136/- per year, as opposed to the price of Rs.8800/- per month from Natco. In addition, the Controller stated that while the drug might be available in metropolitan areas (such as Mumbai, Delhi, Chennai and Kolkata) it was not available throughout the country. Even then the Controller said that the drug was frequently in short supply even in cities and that this was significant because it is a "life saving drug" and not a "luxury item." Finally, the Controller noted that Bayer's worldwide sales increased from $165M in 2006 to $934M in 2010. "These figures clearly demonstrate the neglectful conduct of the Patentee as far as India is concerned," he wrote.
The Controller also disregarded Bayer's argument that sales of another Indian generic company, Cipla, should be taken into account in determining whether the Indian market was being reasonably satisfied, noting that Bayer had sued Cipla in Delhi and asked for an injunction to stop these infringing sales. (In this regard, later in the decision the Controller characterizes this argument as "indulging in two-facedness" and "defend[ing] the indefensible.") In so doing, the Controller also enunciated an Indian-centric philosophy, stating that "the mandate of law is not just to supply the drug in the market but to make it available in a manner such that substantial portion of the public is able to reap the benefits of the invention" and that "[i]f the terms are unreasonable such as high cost of nRS.2,80,000/-, availability is meaningless." (This aspect of the decision was illustrated by the Controller's calculation that, at Bayer's prices it would take the "common man" (the lowest-paid government worker) 3.5 years' wages to afford one month's supply of the drug, but Nexavar extends life for the kidney cancer patient by only 4-6 years and the liver cancer patient by only 6-8 months.) In coming to these determinations, the Controller cited a Bulletin from the World Health Organization; a research article on the "impoverishing effects" of the affordability of medicines in the developing world from PLoS; and an affidavit from James Packard Love, Director of Knowledge Ecology International and co-chair of the Trans-Atlantic Consumer Dialog Policy Committee on Intellectual Property Rights. (Perhaps) needless to say, these sources did not support Bayer's petition that the Indian government deny a compulsory license to Natco.
For its part, Bayer made the patently correct argument that the cost of drugs supports the pipeline of future drug development and that Bayer "continued to invest major sums into further development of Sorafenib" for treating other cancer types. Bayer also noted that its investment in new drug development amounted to 8 billion Euros from 2007 to date, and that it takes more than 2 million Euros to bring a new drug to market. Further research is in the public interest, Bayer argued, and granting Natco a compulsory license would harm the pubic interest in this regard. In what appears to be an effort to avoid a complete defeat, Bayer also argued that a compulsory license should not benefit those in India ("the Rich class" and "the middle class") who could afford the drug at Bayer's price in an attempt to provide the drug to the "common man" who could not (supporting this argument with affidavits from representatives of the Indian medical and insurance industries). (The Controller did not reject this argument but questions why Bayer had not instituted such a graduated pricing regime itself.) But this varying level of the ability to pay, with the varying effects on the question of whether the price was "reasonably affordable" should be sufficient, Bayer argued, to preclude grant of a compulsory license to Natco, since it is a "sine qua non" (or "condition precedent") for a compulsory license that a drug not be available at a "reasonably avoidable price" (although this argument suffered from the fact that the availability of Nexavar® at a "reasonably affordable price" was dependent on sales by Cipla).
The Controller's decision, in favor of granting a compulsory license, was based on his determination that the question of whether a drug was available at a "reasonably affordable price has to be construed predominantly with reference to the public" and under the "admitted facts" of this case these considerations fell in favor of granting the license.
The Controller also considered the fact that Bayer did not "work" the invention in India. Here, the law was construed with regard to whether the invention was worked "to the fullest extent possible" and here it clearly was not (upon evidence that Bayer had "worked" the patented invention "extensively" in other countries while having the industrial capacity to work the patent, i.e., produce Nexavar®, in india). "Minimal" working is not enough, according to Natco, while Bayer argued that the extent of working a patented invention depends on the invention and, for Nexavar® the "small global demand" justifies the "strategic decision" to make the drug in Germany.
In making his decision, the Controller noted that the term "worked in the territory of India" had not been defined in the Indian Patent Act, and so he needed to construe the term with regard to "various International Conventions and Agreements in intellectual property," the 1970 Patent Act and the legislative history. But the Controller seemed more interested in addressing the "crucial argument" of the patentee that the applicant's construction of the term was incorrect because the phrase "default of the patentee to manufacture in India to an adequate extent and supply on reasonable terms the patented article" was deleted from the Act. He decided that this was "one face of the coin," but that the other was that the phrase was deleted from Section 84(1)(a) with regard to the patented article being "reasonable available to the public" in favor of Section 84(1)(c) which "was made a separate ground for grant of a compulsory license."
In this light, the Controller considered the relevant provisions of the Paris Convention, the TRIPS agreement and the Indian Patents Act of 1970 and decided that the combination of Article 27(1) of TRIPS and Article 5(1)(A) of the Paris Convention supported an interpretation that failure to manufacture Nexavar® in India supported the grant of a compulsory license to Natco (which it termed "reasonable fetter" on Bayer's patent rights). Ultimately, however, the Controller found ample justification for the compulsory license in Section 83(b) of the Patent Act, which states that "[p]atents are not granted merely to enable patentees to enjoy a monopoly for importation of the patented article" and Section 83(c) that "the grant of a patent right must contribute to the promotion of technological innovation and to the transfer and dissemination of technology." Coupled with the provisions of Section 83(f) that a patent should not be abused, the Controller construed Indian patent law to require that a patentee work a patented invention in India or license another do to so.
After refusing to adjourn the proceedings based on Section 86 of the law (finding, inter alia, that Bayer had not established any justifiable reason for its "delay" in working the patent in India), the Controller established the terms of the compulsory license, wherein:
i. the right to make and sell sorafenib is limited to applicant (no sublicensing)
ii. the compulsorily licensed drug product can be sold only for treatment of liver and renal cancer;
iii. the royalty shall be paid at a rate of 6%
iv. the price is set at Rs.74/- per tablet, which equals Rs. 8,800/- per month;
v. the applicant commits to provide the drug for free to at least 600 "needy and deserving" patients per year
vi. the compulsory license is not assignable and non-exclusive, with no right to import the drug
vii. No right for the licensee to "represent publicly or privately" that its product is te same as Bayer's Nexavar®
viii. Bayer has no liability for Natco's drug product, which must be physically distinct from Bayer's dosage form
The license was granted on March 9, 2012.
What lessons can be learned from Bayer's experience? Some seem self-evident: patents granted in India come encumbered with a responsibility to produce the patented article in India, either by the patentee itself or by licensing a local Indian company. Second, political realities and economics, particularly for drugs, require some mechanism for providing drugs to those who genuinely cannot afford them. Third, these efforts must be both effective and public; token efforts, specifically efforts that supply much less than the actual demand, will be deemed insufficient. Finally, by licensing rather than being forced to license, patentees can negotiate (perhaps with more than one local company) rather than having the Patent Controller decide the terms (and those terms can be kept confidential). While the Controller here was careful to craft the license to prevent the licensee from exporting the drug, not all compulsory licensees will necessarily be so limited, an important consideration in view of the risks attendant on a licensed competitor being able to supply the global market. The lesson is again learned that foreign drug companies are no match for local drug manufacturers who promise to provide drugs at affordable prices to citizens of India who could not otherwise afford them. In view of the near certainty that licenses under these circumstances will be granted, it behooves Western drug companies to take the initiative to avoid the outcome Bayer suffered last week.
There is a controversy with respect to third aspect in the compoulsory license provisions. The patentee need to manufacture the patented invention in India. Most of the companies do not have manufacturing facilites in India. In such scenario, this provision can be invoked to grant compulsory license to the generic industry. Therefore, the most of the patents are prone and succesptible to the compoulsory license based on the aforesaid criteria. This provision needs interpretation or judicial review by the courts.
Posted by: senthil kumar | March 16, 2012 at 06:03 AM
This is extremely useful and timely.
Just to note, you allude to a "Catch 22" but don't really flesh it out later. Your prescription to be sure to have access plans in place and to either mfgr or license mfgr in India is really good to know.
Posted by: Robert Cook-Deegan | March 16, 2012 at 07:00 AM
Dear Bob:
To be clear, I think the "Catch 22" is that the Western drug companies are required to "work" the patented invention under circumstances where the return on the investment is mandated to be low or non-existent, in view of the Controller's continued characterization of the drug price as being "exorbitant." In the Indian national context he is correct, but that won't sit very well with many corporate boards of directors.
I was also struck (but don't think an n=1 is enough to generalize) at the number of patients in need of the drug (around 8,000/yr) and the small proportion of them that Natco is required to supply free or nearly free of charge (600). It seems like this would be a number that, even if doubled or tripled would not impact the bottom line too much, but that might go a long way towards immunizing the next Western drug company from the same outcome.
Thanks for the comment.
Posted by: Kevin E. Noonan | March 16, 2012 at 09:27 AM
A huge problem with construing "working the invention" is the prohibition of method of treatment claims in India. The patentee is forced to use "Swiss style" claims, which typically are directed to "the use of [drug X] in the manufacture of a medicament..." This locates the patented activity at the patentee's manufacturing plant, rather than in India where the drug is prescribed and administered. In many countries with a "working" requirement, this problem is solved by statutes specifying that sales, or even offers for sale, are sufficient to satisfy the "working" requirement. I don't think this is the case in India.
The law has the effect of forcing innovator companies to sell patented drugs at cost, or at minimal profit, so as to render it an unattractive target for an Indian generic company. This should certainly be possible, given the economies of scale available to a global manufacturer, and at first glance you might think the only downside is a low profit margin on sales in India.
The problem is that any national law that severely restricts profits on patented drugs foists the costs of pharmaceutical R&D onto consumers in other countries, where prices can be raised to compensate for the low profits in regulated markets. U.S. consumers are already subsidizing low prices elsewhere, which is why they're flocking to Canadian (and pseudo-Canadian) on-line pharmacies.
Posted by: James Demers | March 16, 2012 at 12:00 PM
Dear James:
Agreed - but the point is that if “you can’t win” in India if you are a branded Western drug company under WTO/TRIPS any more than you could under earlier international patent regimes, then Western drug companies need to come up with other strategies.
One answer is to coopt – partner with a generic in India with an exclusive license that provides a token amount of the drug to the poor, and make a deal with Indian health care and insurance companies so that there is a graduated increase in the cost of a drug with income – so the rich and super-rich pay Western prices, the middle class pay something akin to what Natco will charge under its compulsory license and include some token number of the poor who pay nothing. By “working” the invention in India, and having a local partner, and providing drug free of charge to (some of) the poor, many if not most of the grounds of granting the compulsory license here would be avoided.
Here, besides the compulsory license it is likely that Natco will try to get out from under the 6% royalty in 2 years by invoking the provisions in Indian law that permit the patent to be revoked.
The advantages of partnering, besides avoiding decisions like the Controller’s here, is that you can prevent your partner from selling API to generic companies abroad – notice that this compulsory license prohibits importing and says it is limited to sales in India but I can think of ways an Indian court could construe this language that would permit export. The goal should be keeping the Indian genie in the bottle, if possible.
The other approach is through the WTO or by erecting barriers to Indian generics in Western countries – which is politically unwise and won’t work.
Thanks for the comment.
Posted by: Kevin E. Noonan | March 16, 2012 at 03:34 PM
My statement, including a link to my Affidavit in the case is available here: http://www.keionline.org/node/1384 I make a few comments that may add some perspective to the case. Not only was the Bayer price ($69k/year) un-affordable in India, Bayer wasn't making much of an effort to supply the market. Bayer said it only sold 493 packages of the drug in 2011, enough for 49 patients to take a yearly dose. India is a country of 1.2 billion people. In terms of R&D, Bayer refused to provide any details of its outlays on the development of Nexavar, despite having been asked to do so. This was a product developed with Onyx Pharmaceuticals, with a fair amount of information on the record about R&D costs from independent sources. I think the days of claiming R&D costs are the main issue in the case, and then refusing to provide any relevant evidence about the outlays on the drug on question, are over. The Bayer PR agents are quoting from Forbes articles about drug development costs, as if this had any real relevance to the Nexavar case, and as if Bayer was somehow pricing its products according to its R&D costs, which is clearly not the case. At the end of the day, who expects developing countries to accept that their citizens will be priced out of the market for cancer drugs for the life of patents? Any system to support R&D that does not work for 80 percent of the global population is flawed, and needs to be changed.
Posted by: James Love | March 17, 2012 at 04:33 PM